In the West, Brexit and the rise of right wing populists such as Donald Trump in the US and Viktor Orban in Hungary have been blamed on globalisation. In particular, many have argued that unchecked international migration — a prominent form of globalisation — has generated a “nativist” backlash.

The developing world has long been accustomed to such a backlash. However, the focus of nativist ire in developing countries is frequently domestic rather than international migration.

In India, prominent examples of such backlash include the nativist or “sons of the soil” politics of Mumbai and Assam.

In our new book, Nativism and Economic Integration across the Developing World , we document the extent of the backlash against domestic migrants across the developing world. Across the developing world, economic growth and integration have been accompanied by a surge in internal or domestic migration. This migration brings human resources where they are valued the most. At the same time, migration and natural population growth increase economic competition and stretch the resources of the places where migrants end up.

Nativist politics

As in Mumbai, “original” residents have frequently resisted such developments. Migration is especially likely to lead to nativist politics in places where elections are held at local levels, giving politicians reason to define and privilege “locals” against outsiders. Political decentralisation pushed by international institutions such as the World Bank creates new tiers of sub-national governance that can be easily captured by nativists.

Until recently, scholars lacked systematic data on domestic migration. Through painstaking work, a team of scholars in Australia have put together “migration matrices” for 21 developing countries. We draw on these data to examine the association between internal migration and nativism in various forms.

As we show in our book, domestic migration was associated with the rise of “indigenous parties” in Latin America, which have catered to the demands of indigenous communities, particularly over land.

Data from 526 regions in 21 countries show that there is a strong positive relationship between internal migration and domestic riots. If we look at the data for individual countries, internal migration and riots are positively correlated in 18 of 21 countries. (Two of the remaining countries didn’t have riots. In Senegal, the association between migration and riots is weakly negative.)

Efforts to examine the effects of migration on nativism have typically faced two related problems.

First, many hard-to-measure factors — such as socio-economic opportunities — could explain both nativism and where migrants go.

Second, the direction of causality could be reversed: not only can migration spark nativism, but nativism likely affects patterns of migration as well.

To address these concerns, we focus on natural disaster-induced migration in India. Flooding and droughts are surprise “pushes” to migration. Compared to planned migration, disaster-induced migration is less correlated with the “pull” factors that are characteristics of migrant-receiving regions.

Anti-migrant politics

For example, internal migration is frequently associated with the rise of anti-migrant politics, as parties cater to nativist sentiments or as new parties emerge to cater to such sentiments.

In Maharashtra, domestic migration fuelled the rise of the Shiv Sena, which railed against South Indian migrants until the 1970s, then switched its focus to Muslim migrants in the 1980s and 1990s, and has since targeted North Indians, particularly Biharis. We show that when natural disasters pushed migrants into certain districts of Maharashtra, those districts were more likely to support the Shiv Sena in subsequent elections.

India’s local governments also favour so-called natives, discriminating against domestic migrants. State governments hire few out-of-State migrants.

The Indian government implemented large scale decentralisation reforms in the early-1990s, creating over 200,000 village, taluk, and district level sub-national governments overnight.

Since competitive elections are held at every level, politicians face strong electoral incentives to define and cater to their own constituents. State governments hired fewer domestic migrants after the decentralisation reforms.

Internal migration is one of the surest paths to economic development. As people move across sub-national boundaries, they exercise their rights to freedom of movement, and improve their lot. By impeding migration, nativism is a barrier to realising the promise of migration.

How then can we better realise the promise of migration, while reducing the backlash against it? Central governments can redistribute resources to migrant-receiving areas to help them cope with the influx of people, and to migrant-sending areas, to reduce migration.

We have found that the Indian central government is more generous with allocations to States that are controlled by the prime minister’s allies.

New Delhi is most likely to manage the challenge of internal migration well if the government draws its power from a large coalition of States.

Bhavnani is an Associate Professor in the Department of Political Science at the University of Wisconsin–Madison, and Lacina is an Associate Professor in the Department of Political Science at the University of Rochester. This article is by special arrangement with the Centre for the Advanced Study of India, University of Pennsylvania.

comment COMMENT NOW